About
Research
Resources
Meetings
Links

Research - Problems and Limitations

November 1st meeting
James' notes on the purpose of money and its problems:

Beginning with the obvious, money is simply a medium of exchange. Money is anything that a group of people accepts as a stand-in for goods and services. The hand-waving mystification of academics and bankers notwithstanding, it really doesn't go deeper than that. Any complexity to the topic is introduced by the complexity of group psychology, not by the technology of money itself.

Continuing with the obvious, individual human beings have not been self-sufficient for a very long time, and probably not ever. Each of us needs and wants things that someone else has or does. The options for the routine and systematic exchange of these things, these goods and services, are limited. I can think of only three.

One, each of us provides our goods and services for free, in the expectation that our needs and wants will be filled by others doing the same thing. This option has been tried many times through history, and its persistent failure probably indicates a conflict with basic human nature, to put it politely.

Two, for each thing we want or need, we find someone who can provide it, and who also wants something we can provide. This happy double coincidence is rare, and can't be expected to satisfy the needs of any but the simplest of subsistence economies in which only a small set of basic, low-value goods are traded.

The third option is to invent or discover a form of money: artifacts that can represent any good or service and which more or less maintain their value over time. This is the only option for sophisticated economies with a wide variety of goods and services, some of them of such high value that barter is made practically impossible.

Money, in effect, sits between a body of goods and a body of buyers and mediates exchange. The value of money, just like the value of goods and services, is described by the venerable law of supply and demand. If there is plenty of money in circulation for relatively few goods, the value of money goes down and (which is to say the same thing) prices go up. This is inflation, and there tends to be lots of consumer confidence during inflation. There's lots of money flying around, and people are encouraged to spend theirs too. The down-side to this inflationary euphoria is that it tends to get out of control and end either in the currency inflating itself to worthlessness or a devastating correction. In such a correction, the supply of money dries up, as it did in the Great Depression of the 1930's when people and especially banks were too scared to spend it and held on to it. Consequently, the value of money goes up and prices go down. There's very little money in circulation and people are scared to let theirs go. The trick is to avoid either of these damaging extremes.

Because stability of supply is so obviously crucial to the success of a form of money, precious metals like silver and gold are an obvious option. The supply of precious metal is naturally limited. With rare exceptions, even large gold finds are not sufficient to upset the balance of supply of money and demand for services. They are also arbitrarily divisible, can be mixed with other (base) metals, and a lot of value (in equivalent goods or services) can be carried around in a small pouch. For most of history, money has been precious metal.

The same thing that made precious metal an attractive choice for money has in the past century made it a poor one: its supply cannot be manipulated. With increasing expectations for continued growth and prosperity from our economic system there is a corresponding demand for control over prices. Ideally, the amount of money in circulation should always correspond to the sum total of goods and services available for purchase (aggregate supply). If the total body of available goods and services shrinks, so too should the money in circulation so that those goods do not become overpriced. If more goods and services are created, the money in circulation should increase to match. This is much easier to manage with paper than with metal.

For these and other reasons, paper has become the money of the past century or two.

Whether an economy uses paper or metal, banks will be happy to store your money for you. Not only that, but they create money, and this is perhaps the most critical and suspicious fact about a bank.

A bank has two fundamental functions: it stores money and it lends money. It is in the lending of money that money is created. Say a person deposits $100 with a bank. They naturally assume that this money is theirs to be withdrawn and put into circulation at any time. A certain amount actually does get withdrawn and circulated. The bank, however, doesn't keep what remains in the account ready for withdrawal; it lends it out. Under current Canadian law, they can lend up to $97 of the $100 deposit, leaving only $3 ready to hand over on demand. The borrower naturally assumes that his $97 loan is his money, available to be withdrawn and put into circulation at any time. This loaned money is created money. It is money that is available for circulation in the economy that was not available, did not exist, before the loan. Before the loan, there was $100 available to circulate. After the loan, there is $197 available for circulation. Money, $97 to be exact, has been created simply at the decision of an account manager and a few strokes of a pen or taps at a keyboard.

I wish there were more mystery to it than this, but there isn't. The obvious and fatal flaw is that if both the borrower and lender want to withdraw the entirety of what they naturally assume is their money, only one can do so. The early bird gets the worm, the late-comer gets nothing, and the bank is broken and must cease operations. There is no deeper mystery.

The operation of a bank is dependent on the statistical regularity that of the total funds deposited, only a small percentage will be demanded on any given day of operation. As with other systems dependent on statistical regularities, there are aberrations, and the system fails. No engineer could design such a system and keep his job. However, like every other aspect of the economy, banks are a psycho-social phenomenon and can't be held to the same high standards as congenial, predictable engineering materials. There is also the bald fact that banks well entrenched and it's hard to imagine a force capable of displacing them from the economy, even if their harmfulness to the public good was conclusively demonstrated.

I don't know yet whether to consider banks and their operations a fundamental flaw in the economic system. Their usefulness as a deposit institution is unquestioned, and the modern economy depends in very large part on the increased money in circulation that results from loans. It is difficult, though not impossible, to imagine a system in which every loan to a borrower reduced the amount of funds available to the depositor. It would require a very enlightened depositor. There are also other flaws in the economic system that seem to over-ride any effect of banking sleight of hand.

back

 all articles and research ©